Issuing a Central Bank Digital Currency: Possible Motives, Characteristics and Consequences

By | November 21, 2019

Courtesy of Christian Pfister*

In 2018, the Bank for International Settlements conducted a survey to which 63 central banks responded. According to the results, 70% of the central banks were then (or planned to be soon) engaged in central bank digital currency (CBDC) work. However, only three central banks reported that they were likely to issue a CBDC within the next six years. Why would a central bank issue a CBDC? How would it work? And what may be the intended, and perhaps unintended, consequences? This post, which summarizes my recent paper, attempts to answer these questions.

Motives

It is useful to draw a distinction between a wholesale CBDC (W–CBDC) and a retail CBDC (R–CBDC). The former would be accessible only to financial institutions, while the latter would be accessible to the general public, including financial institutions.

Wholesale central bank digital currency

Issuing a CBDC would be the only way to allow the circulation of central bank money on a blockchain and would provide a perfectly safe and liquid payment instrument. As a result, recourse to the blockchain would become more attractive to financial institutions.

Promoting financial innovation and lowering transactions costs through the use of blockchain could be motives for issuing a W-CBDC. Because the underlying technology (the Distributed Ledger Technology – DLT) is relatively low-cost, the issuance of a CBDC may also improve the contestability of the payments industry by supporting competition through the entry of new providers.

Retail central bank digital currency

Holding digitalized central bank reserves is presently open to select financial institutions (mainly banks). Furthermore, bank deposits, which are also digitalized, exhibit residual liquidity and credit risks in spite of being insured. Finally, fiat currency, which is accessible to the general public, is not digitalized. Issuing a R-CBDC would fill a gap in the supply of liquid financial assets and break the current incompatibility triangle between universal access, security, and digitalization of liquid financial assets (see Chart below). R-CBDC would also allow central banks to keep a direct relationship with the public in countries where, as in Sweden, the demand for fiat money is decreasing sharply.

 

Issuing a R-CBDC could also contribute to reducing the social costs of retail payment services. These costs are estimated at close to 1% of GDP in the Euro area, half of which correspond to the costs of payments in cash. Moreover, issuing a R-CBDC should support financial inclusion, notably in emerging countries, where the banking system is often loosely present, less efficient, or considered untrustworthy. Furthermore, public authorities in emerging countries might be concerned that stablecoins, such as Libra, will replace the sovereign currency. Finally, in a growing digitalized retail payments system, R-CBDC could help maintain the level of the monetary base, thereby preserving seigniorage and the independence of the central bank in the longer run.

Characteristics of a CBDC

The first common characteristic of a CBDC would be that only the central bank can create or destroy it. Second, in order not to break the uniformity of the payment system, the central bank would issue and exchange at par with the other forms of central bank money (banknotes and reserves). This would ensure the fungibility of the monetary base; and by implication, the CBDC’s supply should be perfectly elastic. It could be difficult to impose constraints on the levels of holdings or to set conversion fees, as such frictions might lead to a breaking of parity between the CBDC and the other forms of central bank money, in particular when the demand for central bank money is high (e.g., bank runs, financial crises). Like banknotes and electronic money, but unlike reserves, it should be possible to transact in the CBDC on a 24/7/365 and peer-to-peer basis.

Specificities of a W-CBDC

As mentioned above, only financial institutions would be entitled to hold a W-CBDC. In order to avoid uncontrolled dissemination of the W-CBDC (which might result in it being used in illicit transactions), and preserve the confidentiality of transactions, W-CBDC would need to be issued on a permissioned blockchain. Only financial institutions and the central bank would have access to this blockchain. And unlike reserves, W-CBDC would circulate outside of the central bank books, while remaining traceable by the central bank through the distributed ledger.

As reserves are remunerated, it seems unavoidable to also remunerate the W-CBDC, in order to keep reserves and the W-CBDC at par.

Central banks currently open accounts only to resident institutions (having a branch is sufficient in many countries). Allowing non-resident financial institutions to participate in the blockchain accepting the W-CBDC would create an unprecedented situation. It would also imply a high degree of international coordination and represent an important step in the internationalization of the currency, via its use on financial markets. This would be especially true for the first W-CBDC-issued reserve currency. However, a possible drawback could be greater instability in the demand for central bank money.

Specificities of a R-CBDC

R-CBDC would likely be open to both residents and non-reisdents. Indeed, it would be difficult to prohibit non-residents from holding a R-CBDC since, in many countries, they can already hold cash and bank deposits in various currencies.

Issuing a monetary asset directly to the public would require fulfilling regulatory requirements, specifically: know-your-customer, anti-money laundering, and combating the financing of terrorism obligations. However, most central banks lack direct experience in managing individuals’ accounts and would like to avoid the reputational risk of a R-CBDC being used in fraudulent transactions. Thus, the distribution of a R-CBDC would likely be intermediated. Moreover, there would, a priori, be little interest in having users validate transactions. Accordingly, a R-CBDC is not likely to be issued on a blockchain, or at least it would not be on a public one.[1]

Several issues arise:

  • Should the R-CBDC be token-based (also called value-based) or account-based? In the first model, R-CBDC transactions would be supported by a physical vector (card, smartphone, etc.). In the second model, financial intermediaries would open R-CBDC accounts for their customers. This model may lend itself to more frequent use of the R-CBDC in transactions, if for instance, wages were paid in R-CBDC.
  • Should the R-CBDC be legal tender, like cash, so that it cannot be refused for transaction settlement? Being legal tender would certainly support the demand for R-CBDC, but it may not be indispensable. Indeed, economic agents do not always know exactly what legal tender is, and use cash instead of other means of payment because they find it cheap and convenient.
  • How should central banks respond to the public’s request for anonymity? Public authorities would not support a fully anonymous R-CBDC. One possibility would be to authorize anonymity only up to a certain amount over a given period. A more open approach could be that, as is presently the case for card payments, anonymity applies only vis-à-vis the counterparty and not vis-à-vis the financial intermediary managing the account.
  • Should the R-CBDC be remunerated? Remunerating – paying interest – on the R-CBDC would make the cental bank a competitor to the banks for deposit collection. It may also lead to real, or perceived, conflicts of interest. For instance, does the central bank raise its policy rate AND the rate of remuneration of the R-CBDC to fight inflation or to collect more deposits? Conversely, an interest-bearing R-CBDC would have advantages from a monetary policy point of view (see next section).

Consequences

A distinction can be drawn between the consequences for (1) the economy and the financial system, (2) monetary policy, and (3) financial stability.

Economy and financial system

By increasing competition and generating productivity gains, both in payment services and beyond (financial services, retail industry, etc.), the issuance of a CBDC would represent a supply shock that would support economic growth. Moreover, the issuance of a R-CBDC would support demand by making it possible to carry out transactions that do not currently take place due to monetary and non-monetary costs, as well as security and privacy concerns.

At the international level, the issuance of a CBDC could exert a disciplining effect on the monetary policies of certain, irresponsible, countries. Furthermore, if financial assets are issued in CBDC and international investors favor them in their asset allocation, this could result in higher exchange rate volatility, particularly in times of stress.

Regarding the financial consequences of the two sorts of CBDC:

  • A W-CBDC would be universally accessible 24/7/365. This would allow its users to make transactions even when financial markets and central banks are closed. One consequence may be the development of an intraday market for W-CBDC, in line with the trend toward real-time payments;
  • The issuance of a R-CBDC could put a floor – possibly at zero if the R-CBDC is not remunerated – to bank deposit rates. In the case of Sweden, the increase in the cost of bank resources could amount to between 0 and 22 basis points, depending on the level of the policy rate and on the spread between this rate and the e-krona rate, with a possible null pass-through in case of a negative policy rate. The interest rate on R-CBDC could be set strictly below the interest rate on the W-CBDC if the central bank wishes to separate the circulation of the two forms of CBDC. Regarding the loss of bank deposits resulting from the issuance of a R-CBDC, it could be limited: in Sweden, it is assessed that a little less than 5% of bank deposits could be transferred towards the e-krona. Finally, if the distribution of the R-CBDC is intermediated, as is likely, banks would not lose access to the information on their customers’ accounts.

 Monetary policy

The main objective of monetary policy is price stability. Starting from a situation in which inflation would be below target, it could transitorily be more difficult to achieve this final objective as a result of the positive supply shock following the issuance of a CBDC, unless the demand shock created by R-CBDC issuance is large enough to offset the disinflationary impact of the supply shock. The consequences for the implementation of monetary policy and for its transmission mechanisms would be more important, and perhaps, permanent.

CBDC issuance could:

  • Result in a more volatile and harder to forecast demand for central bank money; in particular, as a result of the demand from non-residents and in periods of financial stress.
  • Offer an opportunity to widen access to central bank money to payment service providers for the W-CBDC and the R-CBDC, and to financial institutions beyond just banks for the W-CBDC.
  • Lead to the adoption of a real-time monetary policy, echoing the development of an intraday market for W-CBDC, and more generally, the broadening of real-time payments.

An important issue for monetary policy implementation relates to the CBDC rate of interest. As the CBDC would be a part of the monetary base, its remuneration should be compared to those of the other components: banknotes, which are not remunerated, and reserves which, in the Eurosystem, are remunerated at the policy rate—the main refinancing operations rate—for required reserves, and the deposit facility rate for excess reserves.[2] For the W-CBDC, the simplest solution would be to remunerate it as reserves and let banks use W-CBDC to fulfill their reserve requirements. Regarding the R-CBDC, a rate below the one on excess reserves could be applied, in order to take both the convenience yield of holding it into account (the same reason that cash is not remunerated), and dissuade institutions from holding the R-CBDC, thus keeping it for public use.

Whether the R-CBDC is remunerated or not, would affect monetatry policy transmission mechanism:

  • If the R-CBDC is remunerated in a non-symbolic manner, the interest channel should be strengthened and the pass-through of its changes to bank deposit rates would be one-for-one, as long as the policy rate is positive. Conversely, Armelius et al. (2018) ssess that the credit channel could be weakened if banks reduce their supply of loans as a result of a lower income on the management of deposits. Nevertheless, if competition for the distribution of credit is weak, the pass-through of the rise in banks’ cost of resources would be easier. Finally, unless currency is eliminated or an exchange rate for it is set, which could be done independently of the issuance of a R-CBDC, the latter should leave the effective lower bound (i.e. the negative interest rate at which economic agents start to substitute out of bank deposits into cash) unaffected. However, when the interest rate on R-CBDC is negative, it could be easier for banks to pass through negative interest rates onto deposits. This would strengthen the transmission mechanism and also support financial stability by preserving banks’ profitability.
  • If the R-CBDC is not remunerated, the effective lower bound would be raised to zero. Furthermore, the zero lower bound could apply also to securities since future short-term rates could in principle not be lower than zero, with a short-term risk-free asset (i.e. R-CBDC) available in the future in potentially unlimited amount at a zero interest rate.

Financial stability

Concerns have been voiced that R-CBDC issuance may facilitate bank runs and exacerbate liquidity strains. However, having the central bank as the most important depositor, through its refinancing of banks, should reassure the public. Indeed, the central bank is unlikely to withdraw its deposits precipitously since it faces no liquidity constraint. Furthermore, the risk of bank runs taking place just on the basis of rumors should diminish, since the central bank can be expected to have better access to information than the public.

Moreover, the main motivation for supplying a CBDC—allowing all economic agents to have a perfectly safe digitalized means of payment at their disposal, and thereby preserving economic activity in all circumstances—would be at play in times of runs or crises. Even if runs became more frequent, their negative consequences for the economy should thus be lessened.

Conclusion

Issuing a CBDC could be beneficial to the economy. However, it would raise some rather thorny issues, notably, the respective roles of the central bank and the private sector in the supply of money. This would particularly be the case for a R-CBDC, while a W-CBDC might meet the expectations of strongly internationalized financial institutions. Moreover, when interest rates are positive, an interest bearing R-CBDC could create a trade-off between the effectiveness of monetary policy and the cost of bank intermediation. Therefore, the choice may be between not issuing a CBDC and issuing only W-CBDC. In countries where the dwindling use of cash would lead to the demand for a public digital means of settlement, or financial inclusion is low, issuing a R-CBDC would also be a possibility.

*Banque de France, Adviser to the Governor, Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne and Sciences Po. The views expressed are mine and do not necessarily reflect those of the Banque de France, the Eurosystem, Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne or Sciences Po.

 

[1] However, the use of a permissioned blockchain, in which only the central bank and/or the banks and payment services providers could validate transactions, could be of interest, with a view to integrating smart contracts, notably for the payment of interest if the R-CBDC were remunerated.

[2] Since 2008, the Fed has also been able to remunerate reserves at two different rates but has constantly set them at the same level.

0 thoughts on “Issuing a Central Bank Digital Currency: Possible Motives, Characteristics and Consequences

  1. Alex

    Thanks for this very interesting article indeed.
    5 comments:
    – The question of money creation still needs to be sorted out, as still to-day this is only done by commercial banks
    – Anonymity is a key challenge, as CBDCs could simply allow regulators to track everything we do (which is not possible when using cash). AML implications?
    – Look at the recent communications by the PBOC, actively working on their own CBDC: they intend to keep banks in the middle, but also interestingly want it to be usable even offline, while using blockchain
    – On the other hand, the BIS has recently appointed a project lead to establish a CBDC
    – Libra has probably been a catalyst for central bank’s kicking off their own CBNDC project. The probability for the latter to let a competitor like Libra to emerge as arguably very limited

    Reply
  2. Alex

    Thanks for this very interesting article indeed.
    5 comments:
    – The question of money creation still needs to be sorted out, as still to-day this is only done by commercial banks
    – Anonymity is a key challenge, as CBDCs could simply allow regulators to track everything we do (which is not possible when using cash). AML implications?
    – Look at the recent communications by the PBOC, actively working on their own CBDC: they intend to keep banks in the middle, but also interestingly want it to be usable even offline, while using blockchain
    – On the other hand, the BIS has recently appointed a project lead to establish a CBDC
    – Libra has probably been a catalyst for central bank’s kicking off their own CBNDC project. The probability for the latter to let a competitor like Libra to emerge as arguably very limited

    Reply
  3. Dr A S Johan

    Excellent Article. IN spite of all the challenges, my view is that CBDCs will become a reality sooner than later.

    With that, Cryptocurrencies i.e. cryptos that in any way seek to facilitate payments and hope to be a substitute for fiat money will come under so much regulatory pressure and they could in fact be banned totally. It could become a criminal offence to use a cryptocurrency to pay for anything that could be paid for in CBDCs.

    DeXs and CEXs who facilitate cryptocurrency transactions will face power cuts and be denied internet access if they persist to trade cryptocurrencies.

    The only Cryptos that will remain legal to hold will be those ‘tokens’ that provide some real value like providing a hedge against loss of purchasing power of fiat money or represent ownership of some valuable scarce asset like art etc.

    Dr. A S Johan
    Founder of CryptRight
    http://www.cryptright.io

    Reply
  4. Dr A S Johan

    Excellent Article. IN spite of all the challenges, my view is that CBDCs will become a reality sooner than later.

    With that, Cryptocurrencies i.e. cryptos that in any way seek to facilitate payments and hope to be a substitute for fiat money will come under so much regulatory pressure and they could in fact be banned totally. It could become a criminal offence to use a cryptocurrency to pay for anything that could be paid for in CBDCs.

    DeXs and CEXs who facilitate cryptocurrency transactions will face power cuts and be denied internet access if they persist to trade cryptocurrencies.

    The only Cryptos that will remain legal to hold will be those ‘tokens’ that provide some real value like providing a hedge against loss of purchasing power of fiat money or represent ownership of some valuable scarce asset like art etc.

    Dr. A S Johan
    Founder of CryptRight
    http://www.cryptright.io

    Reply

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *